World Champions in Hospital Privatisation: $e E#ects of Neoliberal Reform on German Employees and Patients Nils Böhlke

Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR

Articles and Chapters ILR Collection

2011

World Champions in Hospital Privatisation: $e E#ects of Neoliberal Reform on German Employees and Patients Nils Böhlke Wirtscha%s- und Sozialwissenscha%liche Institut

Ian Greer Cornell University, i.greer@greenwich.ac.uk

$orsten Schulten Wirtscha%s- und Sozialwissenscha%liche Institut

Follow this and additional works at: hOp://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/articles Part of the Human Resources Management Commons, International and Comparative Labor

Relations Commons, International Business Commons, and the Unions Commons &ank you for downloading an article from DigitalCommons@ILR. Support this valuable resource today!

Lis Article is brought to you for free and open access by the ILR Collection at DigitalCommons@ILR. It has been accepted for inclusion in Articles and Chapters by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@ILR. For more information, please contact hlmdigital@cornell.edu.

World Champions in Hospital Privatisation: $e E#ects of Neoliberal Reform on German Employees and Patients

Abstract [Excerpt] Over the past decade, German hospitals have been privatised at a rate not seen in any other country. In response to massive public-sector debt and the resulting investment backlog, many state and local governments have been privatising hospitals. Le most common arguments for privatisation are repeated in a recent study commissioned by the association of private hospital owners (Bundesverband Deutscher Privatkliniken – BDPK) namely that private hospitals manage in a more eKcient manner and are economically more successful (Augurzky, Beivers et al., 2009). Indeed, in some cases, private for-proMt hospital companies have invested generously and turned ineKcient public hospitals into proMtable private ones. Of interest to us is the cost of this trend, to workers and patients.

Assertions that privatisation has not undermined the quality of care are highly dubious. In German public opinion, there is broad scepticism about the privatisation of hospitals. While there are very few scientiMc studies on the eJects of privatisation on patients, there are a growing number of local ballot initiatives and other campaigns to Mght it. Lere are widespread fears that for-proMt health-care provision would undermine the existing system, which provides universally accessible medical treatment at a relatively high level of quality. Even among physicians, oNen considered the winners of privatisation, there is scepticism (Bundesärztekammer, 2007).

We will argue below that one reason for these problems is the eJect of privatisation on employees. Trade unionists and works councils in privatised hospitals have seen a severe deterioration in working conditions (Ver.di Vertrauensleute und Vorsitzende und Mitglieder von Konzernbetriebsräten und Konzern-Jugend- und Auszubildenden-Vertretungen privater Krankenhauskonzern, 2008). Since personnel accounts for about 60 per cent of hospitals’ overall costs (Statistisches Bundesamt, 2008b), private for-proMt hospitals can only make proMts at the expense of employees. Lese perceptions are supported by the statistics presented in this paper, and trade unions and employees protest — in cooperation with other parts of civil society – almost every planned privatisation.

Drawing on publicly available quantitative data and qualitative interviews, we map out in this paper the trend toward the privatisation of German hospitals. We begin by showing how and why privatisation has proceeded in Germany despite the controversy. Len we examine the eJects of privatisation on workers and patients. We will conclude with some implications for policy and practice.

Keywords neoliberalism, hospitals, Germany, privatization, employee relations, patient care

Disciplines Human Resources Management | International and Comparative Labor Relations | International Business | Unions

Comments Suggested Citation Böhlke, N., Greer, I., & Schulten, T. (2011). World champions in hospital privatisation: $e e#ects of neoliberal

Lis article is available at DigitalCommons@ILR: hOp://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/articles/1047

reform on German employees and patients[Electronic version]. Retrieved [insert date], from Cornell University, ILR School site: hOp://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/articles/1047

Required Publisher Statement © Libri Publishing. Final version published as: Böhlke, N., Greer, I., & Schulten, T. (2011). World champions in hospital privatisation: Le eJects of neoliberal reform on German employees and patients. In J. Lister (Ed.), Europe’s health for sale: $e heavy cost of privatization (pp. 9-28). Faringdon, UK: Libri Publishing. Reprinted with permission. All rights reserved.

Lis article is available at DigitalCommons@ILR: hOp://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/articles/1047

World champions in hospital privatisation The effects of neoliberal reform on German employees and patients

Nils Böhlke

WSI

Ian Greer Leeds University

Thorsten Schulten

WSI

Over the past decade, German hospitals have been privatised at a rate not seen in any other country. In response to massive public-

sector debt and the resulting investment backlog, many state and local governments have been privatising hospitals. The most common

arguments for privatisation are repeated in a recent study commissioned by the association of private hospital owners (Bundesverband

Deutscher Privatkliniken – BDPK) namely that private hospitals manage in a more efficient manner and are economically more successful

(Augurzky, Beivers et al., 2009). Indeed, in some cases, private for-profit hospital companies have invested generously and turned inefficient

public hospitals into profitable private ones. Of interest to us is the cost of this trend, to workers and patients.

Assertions that privatisation has not undermined the quality of care are highly dubious. In German public opinion, there is broad

scepticism about the privatisation of hospitals. While there are very few scientific studies on the effects of privatisation on patients, there

are a growing number of local ballot initiatives and other campaigns to fight it. There are widespread fears that for-profit health-care provision

would undermine the existing system, which provides universally accessible medical treatment at a relatively high level of quality. Even

among physicians, often considered the winners of privatisation, there is scepticism (Bundesärztekammer, 2007).

We will argue below that one reason for these problems is the effect of privatisation on employees. Trade unionists and works councils

in privatised hospitals have seen a severe deterioration in working conditions (Ver.di Vertrauensleute und Vorsitzende und Mitglieder von

Konzernbetriebsräten und Konzern-Jugend- und Auszubildenden-Vertretungen privater Krankenhauskonzern, 2008). Since personnel

accounts for about 60 per cent of hospitals’ overall costs (Statistisches Bundesamt, 2008b), private for-profit hospitals can only make profits

at the expense of employees. These perceptions are supported by the statistics presented in this paper, and trade unions and employees

protest — in cooperation with other parts of civil society – almost every planned privatisation.

Drawing on publicly available quantitative data and qualitative interviews, we map out in this paper the trend toward the privatisation of

German hospitals. We begin by showing how and why privatisation has proceeded in Germany despite the controversy. Then we examine

the effects of privatisation on workers and patients. We will conclude with some implications for policy and practice.

The waves of privatisation

The privatisation of German hospitals has been well documented by the federal statistics office (Statistisches Bundesamt, 2008a) (see

Figure 1). From 1991 to 2007 the proportion of private hospitals has almost doubled and has reached nearly 30 per cent. On the other hand

the proportion of public hospitals has dropped from 46 per cent to about 32 per cent. Over this time, the proportion of private non-profit

hospitals run by the churches and non-profit organisations has been relatively stable.

The total number of public hospitals has dropped from 1,110 in 1991 to 677 in 2007. In the same time the number of private hospitals

has increased from 358 to 620. This decline in the importance of public hospitals has two reasons: closures of public hospitals and the sale of

public hospitals to for-profit hospital chains. This latter process we call material privatisation (see Table 1).

Reasons for privatisation

The reasons for these changes can be found in the precarious situation of public budgets and the fundamental change in the financing

system of German hospitals (Simon, 2008b). Since the early 1970s there has been a so-called “dual financing system” for hospitals, under

which statutory health insurance funds pay for the operational costs, while the federal states (Länder) are responsible for the investments.

Since the early 1990s, this system has been reformed several times in order to reduce costs, mainly by linking reimbursements to the

diagnoses treated and decoupling them from the operating costs of hospitals.

The first important reform came in the early 1990s, when the principle of full-cost recovery wäs abolished. Previously, the costs for the

hospitals were automatically covered by the health insurance funds. Thus pressures on the hospitals to reduce costs rose dramatically and

drastic changes became necessary.

A system of mandatory nationwide case-based reimbursements was introduced in 2004 as the G-DRG-System (German Diagnosis Related

Groups). According to this system, treatments are financed on the basis of defined diagnosis and not on time spent in hospital, as they had

been before. Prices for each diagnosis are calculated for each Land on the basis of average costs in hospitals. This favours hospitals that work

with relatively low costs per diagnosis and leads to increased cost pressure on hospitals to reduce their costs. For some companies, it raises

the possibility of generating significant profits. This has made hospitals increasingly interesting for private investors and created problems for

public-sector owners.

The number of hospitals has dropped by 13.4% since 1991 and the number of hospital beds has declined by 23.8% (Table 1). This has

been accompanied by a 10% decline in full-time-equivalent staff. Additionally, outsourcing has become an important factor. Furthermore,

the altered incentives of the DRG-System have led to a decline in the average length of stay of almost 50% (Statistisches Bundesamt, 2008a).

However, the number of cases has increased by 17.1%. Thus slightly fewer employees treat more cases in a lot less time and the industrial

productivity of German hospitals has risen considerably.

Over the next few years the share of private for-profit hospitals is widely expected to rise, to as much as 40% (Bähr, Fuchs et al., 2006).

One reason for this shift is that many public hospitals remain inefficient. In 2008, one-third of hospitals operated in the red (Augurzky, Budde

et al., 2009) and most of those are public hospitals whose deficits have to be balanced by the local budget of the municipality. From the view

of many local governments, the material privatisation of hospitals is an attractive opportunity to rid themselves of these costs.

The lack of investment by the federal states in hospitals further accelerated the trend towards privatisation. Different studies quantify

the backlog of needed investments between €20b (Augurzky, Budde et al., 2009), €50b (DKG, 2008 or even €100b (Simon, 2008a). From these

privatisations, municipalities hope to receive the needed investment from private investors. Indeed, private hospitals receive more

investment than public ones (Augurzky, Beivers et al. 2009) because their profitability makes it easier for them to receive capital from private

investors. Those higher investments help private for-profit hospitals to improve their competitive position vis-a-vis public hospitals and lead

to rationalisation and thus higher productivity.

Formal privatisation of public hospitals

Intensified competition and cost pressures have led to reorganisations of many public hospitals using structural changes modelled on

those of the private companies. One common approach is formal privatisation. This means that hospitals run directly by local government

departments become fully owned subsidiaries of the states and run under private law. They are still owned by the state, but the decision-

making power becomes relatively independent from the political and administrative processes of government.

As Figure 2 shows, over the last five years the number of state-owned hospitals operating under a public legal form has declined by almost

two-thirds, while the share of public hospitals run under private law has almost doubled. This change has been caused by the increased

competition due to the implementation of the DRG-System. The higher number of potential “veto- players” in the public authorities – i.e.

actors who can obstruct rationalisation through the machinery of local government – is viewed as an obstacle under this context. The largest

example of such a formal privatisation is the Vivantes Kliniken GmbH in Berlin. The company was founded in 2001 and is the result of a merger

of nine city-owned hospitals.

Functional privatisation: outsourcing

In addition to the material and formal privatisation of entire hospitals, the transfer of functions – mostly support services, rather than

direct patient-care functions – into the private sector has played an important role. The outsourced work is either transferred to an external

company (“external outsourcing”) or into a newly established subsidiary of the hospital operator (“internal” outsourcing).

According to a survey of the German hospital association, more than 53% of all hospitals have outsourced cleaning services and more

than 40% their kitchens between 2004 and 2007 (see Table 2). Increasingly, administrative and medical-technical functions are affected as

well. The surprisingly low share of hospitals that have outsourced their laundry operations might be explained by the fact that these services

were already widely outsourced before 2004. This has accompanied a decline in employment in these areas since 2001 that has been

estimated to be as high as 41% (Jaehrling, 2007). Another form of outsourcing – involvement of private capital through public-private

partnerships (PPP) – is usually used for the financing of the construction of new hospital buildings, which after completion are leased by the

public authorities that run the services.

Ownership structure in international comparison

Unlike other types of privatisation, the rapid material privatisation of hospitals is unique to Germany. Currently, among major western

countries only France has a higher share of private for-profit hospitals. However, France’s traditionally strong private sector has declined

nominally over recent years. Germany, by contrast, surpassed the US in terms of private market share by the end of 2007 (Gröschl-Bahr and

Stumpfögger, 2008).

Internationally, there are three different structures of ownership, as Table 3 shows. As in France and Austria, Germany has a mix of

different owners. There are public and private for-profit hospitals as well as a large proportion of hospitals that are private, but non-profit.

These hospitals are mainly run by churches and welfare associations like the Red Cross and their share is slowly declining. In other countries

like the UK, Poland, Sweden and Denmark, hospitals are almost exclusively part of a public health system. The third structure can be found

in Belgium, the Netherlands and the USA, where most hospitals are private and non-profit.

Private hospitals = smaller hospitals?

Although Germany has a long tradition of private hospitals, a qualitative shift in the sector occurred in the early 1990s. In the 1970s and

1980s the private hospitals were exclusively small clinics specialised on lucrative surgeries and treatments. They were not products of

privatisation, but were designed and founded as small private clinics. Because of these origins, while the number of material privatisations

has increased in the 1990s, private for-profit hospitals still account for a significantly lower share of beds and employees than public hospitals.

While public hospitals still have more than 50% of all hospital beds, private for-profit hospitals have just 16%. Even more important is the

role of public hospitals for the employees. More than 56% of all employees work in public hospitals and less than 14% in private for-profit

ones (Figure 3).

For-profit hospitals, however, have been catching up rapidly in size, especially over the past five years. While the share of private for-

profit hospitals has risen by more than 20%, the share of beds in those hospitals has increased by more than 60% (see Figure 4). While the

first wave of privatisation predominantly hit small clinics in the area of the former GDR, this more recent wave is affecting larger hospitals in

western Germany as well. Most observers assume that this wave will continue through 2010. While the effect of the crises on local

government could be eased by the economic stimulus packages of the federal government in 2009, investment from the Länder and income

from the health insurance funds (and thus income for the hospitals) is forecast to deteriorate further (Augurzky, Budde et ah, 2009). Under

these circumstances private hospital chains will offer to intervene as investors, and policy makers will find it difficult to reject their offers.

The trends described above proceeded unevenly in different Länder. In the “new” states in eastern Germany, the share of private for-

profit hospitals is relatively high, partly due to privatisation and partly due to a weaker tradition of church-run provision. In addition, the

share of private hospitals is especially high in western Länder where especially large privatisations have taken place. Hamburg does not have

any public hospitals besides the university hospital and Hessen has privatised two of its three university hospitals. However, generally the

share of private for-profit provision in large western Länder is significantly lower than average.

Oligopolisation of the hospital sector

The privatisation of hospitals has led to the rapid growth of a few hospital chains. The German hospital market is dominated by four major

companies. Two of them are the largest hospital companies in terms of revenue and three in terms of employees. The companies are the

Rhön Kliniken AG, the Helios-Kliniken-Group, the Asklepios Kliniken GmbH and the Sana Kliniken AG.

The major German hospital companies are former family businesses that were founded and dominated by individual physicians. The only

exception is the Sana Kliniken AG, which is run by a group of private insurance companies. The founders of Asklepios, Rhön and Helios play a

major role in the management of these companies. Recently, this has changed a little due to the purchase of Helios by Fresenius SE in 2005

and the withdrawal of the founder of Asklepios in early 2008.

Overall, the basic structure of the German for-profit hospital landscape remains stable. Attempts from private equity funds to enter the

market, like the British firm APAX’s bid via the Swedish health-care company Capio, remain exceptional. However, the resale of private

hospitals to other private companies and private equity funds will probably increase over the next years (Schmidt, 2003; Bähr, Fuchs et al.,

2006). The largest private hospital owners in other countries are more closely tied to financial markets (Stumpfögger, 2007) and the need for

massive investment may undermine the governance practices of these companies.

Competition on labour costs instead of quality

The competition that was created with the abolition of full-cost recovery and the implementation of the DRG-System has been further

intensified due to the increasing importance of the private hospital companies. Besides paying for the operating costs and investments in

their hospitals, private companies have to generate a profit for their owners. Since the DRG-system provides only limited scope for hospitals

to influence their income, profit has to result from cost reductions.

According to the federal statistics office, the share of personnel (labour) costs in 2007 was 61.6% (2008b). For managers, labour costs are

an obvious source of potential savings, and there are several possible ways to reduce them. The major hospitals (those with more than 500

beds) have reduced their share of labour costs since the early 1990s regardless of their ownership. However, the largest reduction has

happened in private for-profit hospitals (see Figure 6).

Table 5 shows the collective bargaining landscape in German hospitals. Private for-profit hospitals derive major cost advantages from

signing collective agreements at the level of the hospital, if they sign any agreement at all (Augurzky, Beivers et al., 2009). Usually, immediately

after the privatisation, private for-profit companies try to reach a new collective agreement (Gröschl-Bahr and Stumpfögger, 2008) and break

away from the federal collective agreement for public services (TVoD) that is perceived as “too inflexible” (Neubauer and Beivers, 2006).

Hence, 85.7% of the employees of public hospitals (excluding physicians) are getting paid according to the federal agreements, compared to

just 14.1% of their colleagues in private for-profit ones. In the latter, 20.3% have a collective agreement at the hospital level and 24% do not

have a collective agreement at all.

The largest group of employees in the private for-profit hospital companies have a collective agreement signed by the Bundesverband

Deutscher Privatkliniken (BDPK – Federal association of German private hospitals) and the Deutschen Handels-und Industrieangestellten-

Verband (DHV). The latter is a member of the Christian federation of trade unions (CGB) that opposes the German federation of trade unions

(DGB) and signs agreements more closely aligned with the demands of the employers. In many other for-profit hospitals, there is a framework

collective agreement that may cover certain terms and conditions of employment, but does not cover salaries. Thus the real proportion of

employees in private for-profit hospitals that do not receive a wage that is secured by collective agreements is higher than the numbers in

Table 6 suggest.

The erosion of collective bargaining is one trend that may be reversing itself. Over the past few years, public-sector trade union Ver.di

has been quite successful in reaching collective agreements with the major hospital chains that contain wages, similar to the federal collective

agreement for public services (Gröschl-Bahr and Stumpfögger, 2008). According to the Association of German Hospitals (DKG), about nine

per cent of hospitals have signed so called “emergency collective agreements” that allow a temporary reduction of wages by ten per cent

(Blum, Offermanns et al., 2007). The majority of those hospitals, however, are public and the purpose of these clauses is to keep them under

the TVoD.

The reduction of costs is an important objective of outsourcing, and the reduction or freezing of wages is the usual result. Outsourcing

usually leads to a situation where employees either have no collective agreements or significantly worse agreements than before. In particular

the workers with assignments that are not directly linked to the patients often have to accept worse agreements than their colleagues

(Jaehrling, 2007). According to internal union sources, cleaning personnel for example usually drop to the minimum wage for their sector,

which is about 30% lower than the respective wage in the TVöD. Employees of the temporary work agencies established by some private and

public hospitals are also paid significantly lower wages. This division of the workforce seems to harm the position of the core staff as well.

Table 6 shows how privatisation has affected the pay of various occupational groups. In 2007 the average cost per full-time-equivalent in

private for-profit hospitals was four per cent lower than in public hospitals. Hence there is not just a lower share of the workers secured by

collective agreement but a general wage drift. Wages of doctors in private for-profit hospitals are slightly higher, while those of employees

in technical, functional and special services are much lower. The wages of nurses, the largest group of hospital workers, are nine per cent

higher in public hospitals.

These changes have widened pay inequalities between occupational groups, with nurses and medical technical staff hit especially hard.

As Figure 7 shows, the average wage of a nurse in a private hospital was just 85.1% that of all employees, down from 90% in 1991. This trend

has been much slower in public hospitals, where the average wage of a nurse in relation to the overall average dropped from 92.6%

Sources: Statistisches Bundesamt, 2008a; Statistisches Bundesamt, 2008b; authors’own calculations

to 89.4%. Generally, nurses in private for-profit hospitals earn just 91.4% of the wages earned by their colleagues in public hospitals

(Statistisches Bundesamt, 2008b).

Effects on working conditions

Competition on the basis of labour costs does not only take place through downward pressures on wages. According to trade unionists

and works council members, the intensification of work has also increased at private hospitals. This has negative effects on both employees

and patients. One major indicator, the ratio of number of patients to the number of staff, has deteriorated sharply (Ver.di Vertrauensleute

und Vorsitzende und Mitglieder von Konzernbetriebsräten und Konzern-Jugend-und Auszubildenden-Vertretungen privater

Krankenhauskonzern, 2008).

Compared with the public hospitals, the staff-to-patient ratio is especially low in private for-profit hospitals. According to the federal

statistics office, the number of occupied beds that one member of staff had to look after is considerably higher than in public hospitals. This

applied across all professional groups (see Figure 8).

Since small hospitals cannot be compared with larger hospitals (they offer different services that require different personnel), here we

compare only hospitals with more than 500 beds. In 2007, in a private for-profit hospital a physician had to care for almost 25% more occupied

beds than his colleague in a public hospital. Each nurse in private for-profit hospitals had to care for more occupied beds as well and this

discrepancy was even greater in medical- technical services (Statistisches Bundesamt, 2008a).

Effects on the quality of care

The hospital sector is facing a politically driven imperative to economise that is self-reinforcing and self-amplifying. Numerous

international studies indicate that the quality of care is declining, with a decreasing number of personnel and a focus on economic success.

In the USA, for example, there is a clear correlation between mortality rate and ownership. In for-profit hospitals it is higher than in non-

profit hospitals (Devereaux et al., 2002). According to a recent study by the Harvard School of Public Health, patients surveyed assessed all

quality criteria to be worse in private for-profit hospitals (Jha, Orav et al., 2008). These studies suggest a strong correlation between patient

satisfaction and the number of nurses.

There are no German empirical studies on the effect of lower staff-to-patient ratios on the quality of care that compare private and public

hospitals. However, there are surveys by the statutory insurance funds that indicate a worse quality of care for their customers in private

hospitals (Braun and Müller, 2006). The major complaint was that patients were discharged home too early. Compared to an earlier

survey in 2002 this sentiment has increased in public hospitals as well, but at a lower level. Overall, the perception of the quality of treatment

was worse in private for-profit hospitals than their public-sector counterparts. However, the private non-profit hospitals received the best

results.

Regarding the results of treatment, patients in public hospitals have seen an improvement in their hospitals in all the main disease

categories. All of these statements indicate obvious trends. Especially compared with the survey in 2002, the experiences in private for-profit

hospitals show a similar tendency. However, in three out of four diagnoses, patients in private for-profit hospitals claimed lower rates of

improvement and healing than in 2002. Unlike public and non-profit hospitals, private for-profit hospitals have seen a deterioration and it is

probable that higher work intensity is one reason (see Figure 9).

The future of German hospitals

Against a background of financial and economic crisis, most observers expect further waves of privatisation over the next few years. The

negative effect of the crisis for the hospital sector has been buffered by the federal government’s economic stimulus packages. However, in

2010 the situation in most hospitals will probably become worse (Augurzky, Beivers et al., 2009). The fiscal problems of the state and local

governments will make it less and less likely that they will finance deficits or increase investment in public hospitals. For the major private

hospital chains, this represents a major opportunity for future acquisitions. Rhön-Kliniken AG, for example, has decided to raise €500m in

capital to buy more hospitals (Handelsblatt, 5 July 2009).

However, there is broad public scepticism about the trend toward privatisation. In a 2008 survey, 63 per cent of the population thought

that hospitals should be public and just six per cent thought all hospitals should be private (DBB, 2008). Already, there have been several

cases of mass protests against hospital privatisation, some of which involved ballot initiatives for a referendum (Mittendorf, 2008). Some of

these have helped to prevent the purchase; and usually when the referendum was unsuccessful it was for procedural reasons, not because

a majority of the population voted in favour of the privatisation. Most of these initiatives have included a broad alliance of trade unions,

physicians, social movement organisations, local politicians and local organisations (Böhlke, Greer and Schulten, 2009). There is little reason

to believe that this protest will abate any time soon.

In the upcoming debate, the main question will be whether marketisation and the introduction of competition are appropriate means to

organise health care. Despite the problems described above, the federal association of private hospitals (BDPK) does not hesitate to demand

even more cost-cutting, since the hospital sector has become a lucrative business. They have continued to ask for more deregulation,

including the abolition of hospital planning by the Länder (BDPK, 2007).

Because of price setting and other regulations, it is still the case that the hospital sector in Germany is not a free market (Bruckenberger,

Klaue et ah, 2006). It is obvious that a “hospital market” differs from classic markets in several ways that make a purely capitalistic organisation

impossible. Health is existential and cannot be abandoned or boycotted. The “customer” cannot withdraw from a service that does not satisfy

his or her needs or autonomously decide which service is necessary. There are thus asymmetries of power and information between patients

and health-care professionals. As a collective good, health-care provision is a basic right for every person that in many countries may not be

withheld from anyone; in Germany this right is grounded in article 2, section 2 of the Basic Law. For these reasons, health systems are

regulated relatively strictly (Deppe, 2002).

High-quality hospital care costs money, which in Germany comes from taxes and insurance contributions. Due to the way the industry is

structured, corporate hospital profits are not accumulated due to the workings of a free market but rather extracted from society using

political processes of reforms. The German Association of Community Hospitals (IVKK) has argued along these lines and added that in health

care profits are an extra cost with little or no benefit, and should therefore be abolished (IVKK, 2008).

Private hospital chains have two main advantages in the German healthcare industry as it is currently structured. First, they have

significantly lower personnel costs and a more intense exploitation of employees. Private for-profit hospitals pay below the collective

agreement and have lower staff-to-patient ratios. It is the task of trade unions to fight for equal conditions across the sector. Second, because

private for-profit hospitals receive pore investment, they enjoy advantages in terms of productivity. It is the responsibility of the public

authorities to increase the level of investments in the public sector to counterbalance this structural disadvantage.

The advantages enjoyed by private for-profit hospitals reflect failures of public policy that have produced a shift of power to private

owners. For many social and economic reasons (Weizsäcker, Orav et ah, 2005), trade unions, civil society and political parties on the left

should, and will, continue to resist the trend toward privatisation.

References

Augurzky, B., A. Beivers, et al. (2009) Bedeutung der Krankenhäuser in privater Trägerschaft. Essen, RWI, Institut für Gesundheitsökonomik,http://www.rwi-essen.de/pls/portal30/docs/FOLDER/PUBUKATIONEN/RWIMAT/RWI_M AT052/M_52_PRIVATEKH.PDF

Augurzky, B., R. Budde, et al. (2009) Krankenhaus Rating Report 2009 – Im Auge des Orkans. Essen, RWI

Bähr, C„ P. Fuchs, et al. (2006) Kliniken-Privatisierungswelle. Frankfurt am Main, DZ Bank AG. 29/03/2006

BDPK (2007) Mehr unternehmerische Freiheit – Krankenhäuser schrittweise entfesseln. Eckpunkte zur Gestaltung des ordnungspolitischen Rahmens für Krankenhäuser nach dem Ende der Konvergenzphase. Bundesverband DeutscherPrivatkliniken,http://www.bdpk.de/media/file/50.2007-02-08_BDPK-Presseerklaerung_Ordnungspolit ischer_Rahmen.pdf

Blum, K., M. Offermanns, et al. (2007) Krankenhaus Barometer. Deutsches Krankenhausinstitut (DKI), http://dki.comnetinfo.de/PDF/Bericht%20KFI%20Barometer%202007.pdf, 29/04/2009

Böhlke, N., I. Greer, T. Schulten (2009) ‘Deutsche Gründlichkeit: Market making and industrial relations in German hospitals’, CERIC Working Paper, Leeds: Centre for Employment Relations Innovation and Change

Braun, B. and R. Müller (2006) Versorgungsqualität im Krankenhaus aus der Perspektive der Patienten. Ergebnisse einer wiederholten Patientenbefragung und einer Längsschnittanalyse von GEK-Routinedaten. Schwäbisch Gmünd, GmünderErsatzkasse-GEK,http://media.gek.de/downloads/magazine/GEK-Studie-Versorgungsqualitaet-Kranken haus.pdf, Juni 2006

Bruckenberger, E., S. Klaue, et al. (2006) Krankenhausmärkte zwischen Regulierung und Wettbewerb.Berlin; Heidelberg, Springer-Verlag

Bundesärztekammer (2007) Zunehmende Privatisierung von Krankenhäusern in Deutschland. Folgen für die ärztlich Tätigkeit. Bundesärztekammer, http://bundesaerztekammer.de/ downloads/Ergebnisbericht_final.pdf, 31/08/2009

DBB (2008) Bürgerbefragung öffentlicher Dienst. Berlin, Deutscher Beamtenbund

Deppe, H.-U. (2002) Kommerzialisierung oder Solidarität? Zur Grundlegenden Orientierung der Gesundheitspolitik. In: H.-U. Deppe und W. Burkhardt. Solidarische Gesundheitspolitik. Alternativen zu Privatisierung und Zwei- Klassen-Medizin. Hamburg, VSA-Verlag: 10-23 Devereaux, P.J., D. Heels-Ansdell, et al. (2004) ‘Payments for Care at private for-profit and private not-for-profit hospitals: a systematic review and meta-analysis’ in Canadian Medical Association Journal, 170(12): 1,817-24

Devereaux, P.J., et al. (2002) ‘A systematic review and meta-analysis of studies comparing mortality rates of private for- profit and private not-for-profit hospitals’ in Canadian Medical Association Journal, 166(11): 1,399-1,406

DKG (2008) Zahlen, Daten, Fakten 2007/08. Düsseldorf, Deutsche Krankenhausgesellschaft

Gröschl-Bahr, G. and N. Stumpfögger (2008) Krankenhäuser, ln: T. Brandt, T. Schulten, G. Sterkel und J. Wiedemuth. Europa im Ausverkauf – Liberalisierung und Privatisierung öffentlicher Dienstleistungen und ihre Folgen für die Tarifpolitik. Hamburg, VSA-Verlag: 165-180

IVKK (2008) Gewinne in Kliniken nachhaltig reinvestieren – für gesetzliche Thesaurierungspflicht. Interessenverband kommunaler Krankenhäuser, press release, 10/10/2008

Jaehrling, K. (2007) Wo das Sparen am leichtesten fällt – Reinigungs- und Pflegehilfskräfte im Krankenhaus. In: G. Bosch und C. Weinkopf. Arbeiten für wenig Geld. Niedriglohnbeschäftigung in Deutschland. Frankfurt am Main, New York, Campus Verlag: 175-210

Jha, A.K., E.J. Orav, et al. (2008) ‘Patients’ Reception of Hospital Care in the United States’ in New England Journal of Medicine, 359(18): 1,921-31

Mittendorf, V. (2008) Bürgerbegehren und Volksentscheide gegen Privatisierungen und die Rolle der Gewerkschaften. In: T. Brandt, T. Schulten, G. Sterkel and J. Wiedemuth. Europa im Ausverkauf. Hamburg, VSA-Verlag: 310-329

Neubauer, G. and A. Beivers (2006) “Privatisierung der Krankenhäuser: modischer Trend oder ökonomische Notwendigkeit?” in: Orientierungen zur Wirtschafts- und Gesellschaftspolitik 109.2006(3): 48-52

Schmidt, C. (2003) “Ein Markt im Umbruch. Kliniken im Fokus privater Ketten und Investoren” in: krankenhaus Umschau 11/2003:1,090-1,095

Simon, M. (2008a) Das Gesundheitssystem in Deutschland. Eine Einführung in Struktur und Funtionsweise. 2., vollständig überarbeitete Auflage, Bern, Verlag Hans Huber

Simon, M. (2008b) Sechzehn Jahre Deckelung des Krankenhausbudgets: Eine kritische Bestandsaufnahme. Hannover, Studie für die vereinte Dienstleistungsgewerkschaft ver.di. https://gesuhdheitspolitik.verdi.de/gesundheit_von_a-z/krankenhaeuser/budgetdeckelung/ data/simon_kritik_der_budgetdeckelung.pdf, 25/05/2009 Statistisches Bundesamt (1993) Kostennachweis der Krankenhäuser 1991. Wiesbaden, Statistisches Bundesamt, December 1993

Statistisches Bundesamt (2008a) Grunddaten der Krankenhäuser 2007. Wiesbaden, Statistisches Bundesamt, 10/12/2008

Statistisches Bundesamt (2008b) Kostennachweis der Krankenhäuser 2007. Wiesbaden, Statistisches Bundesamt, 15/12/2008

Stumpfögger, N. (2007) Krankenhausfusionen und Wettbewerbsrecht. Unternehmenskonzentration im deutschen

http://media.gek.de/
http://bundesaerztekammer.de/
https://gesuhdheitspolitik.verdi.de/gesundheit_von_a-z/krankenhaeuser/budgetdeckelung/

Krankenhausmarkt2003bis2007,http://gesundheitsoziales.verdi.de/branchenpolitik/krankenhausmarkt/data/kra nkenhausmarkt-2007.pdf, 29/04/2009

Ver.di Vertrauensleute und Vorsitzende und Mitglieder von Konzernbetriebsräten und Konzern-Jugend-und Auszubildenden-Vertretungen privater Krankenhauskonzern (2008) Krankenhausfinanzierung: Woher die Gewinne privater Krankenhauskonzerne kommen, Berlin, Offener Brief, An Bundesgesundheitsministerin Ulla Schmidt, An die Gesundheitsministerinnen und -minister der Länder und An die Abgeordneten des Deutschen Bundestages, 02/10/2008

Weizsäcker, E.U. v., E.J. Orav, et al. (2005) Limits to privatisation, London: Earthscan

Please follow and like us: